Офф-топик: Едно интересно четиво

2 views
Skip to first unread message

Чефо

unread,
Nov 9, 2008, 4:51:48 PM11/9/08
to Macedonia Discussion Group
http://harpers.org/archive/2008/06/0082042

Our phony economy

By Jonathan Rowe

From testimony delivered March 12 before the Senate Committee on
Commerce, Science, and Transportation, Subcommittee on Interstate
Commerce. Rowe is codirector of West Marin Commons, a community-
organizing group, in California.

Suppose that the head of a federal agency came before this committee
and reported with pride that agency employees had burned 10 percent
more calories at work last year than they did the year before. Not
only that–they had spent 10 percent more money too. I have a feeling
you would want to know more. What were these employees doing when they
burned those calories? What did they spend that money on? Most
important, what were the results? Expenditure is a means, not an end,
and to assess the health of an agency, or system, you need to know
what it has accomplished, not just how much motion it has generated
and money it has spent. The point seems obvious, yet Congress ignores
it every day when it talks about “the economy.” The administration and
the media do it, too. Every time you say that “the economy” is up, or
that you want to “stimulate” it, you are urging more expenditure and
motion without regard to what that expenditure is and what it might
accomplish, and without regard to what it might crowd out or displace
in the process.

That term “the economy”: what it means, in practice, is the Gross
Domestic Product–a big statistical pot that includes all the money
spent in a given period of time. If the pot is bigger than it was the
previous quarter, or year, then you cheer. If it isn’t bigger, or
bigger enough, then you call Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke up
here and ask him to do some explaining. The what of the economy makes
no difference in these councils. It never seems to come up. The money
in the big pot could be going to cancer treatments or casinos, violent
video games or usurious credit-card rates. It could go toward the $9
billion or so that Americans spend on gas they burn while they sit in
traffic, or the billion plus that goes to such drugs as Ritalin and
Prozac that schools are stuffing into kids to keep them quiet in
class. The money could be the $20 billion or so that Americans spend
on divorce lawyers each year, or the $41 billion on pets, or the $5
billion on identity theft, or the billions more spent to repair
property damage caused by environmental pollution. The money in the
pot could betoken social and environmental breakdown–misery and
distress of all kinds. It makes no difference. You don’t ask. All you
want to know is the total amount, which is the GDP. So long as it is
growing then everything is fine.

I am not talking about an obscure technical measure. This is not stuff
for the folks in the back room. I am talking about what you mean when
you use that term “the economy.” Few words induce such a reverential
hush in these halls. Few words are so laden with authority and
portent. When you say “the economy” is up, no news is better. When you
argue that a proposal will help the economy or hurt it, then you have
played the ultimate trump card in your polemical deck, bin Laden
possibly excepted.

This, by the way, is not an argument against growth. To be reflexively
against growth is as numb-minded as to be reflexively for it. Those
are theological positions. I am arguing for an empirical one. Find out
what is growing and the effects. Tell us what this growth is, in
concrete terms. Then we can begin to say whether it has been good.

The failure to do this is insane. It is an insanity that is embedded
in the political debate and in media reportage, and it leads to
fallacy in many directions. We hear, for example, that efforts to
address climate change will hurt “the economy.” Does that mean that if
we clean up the air we will spend less money treating asthma in young
kids? The atmosphere is part of the economy, too–the real economy,
that is, though not the artificial construct portrayed in the GDP. It
does real work, as we would discover quickly if it were to collapse.
Yet the GDP does not include this work. If we burn more gas, the
expenditure gets added to the GDP. But there is no corresponding
subtraction for the toll this burning takes on the thermostatic and
buffering functions that the atmosphere provides. (Nor is there a
subtraction for the oil we take out of the ground.) Yet if we burn
less gas, and thus maintain the crucial functions of the atmosphere,
we say “the economy” has suffered, even though the real economy has
been enhanced.

With families the logic is the same. By the standard of the GDP, the
worst families in America are those that actually function as families–
that cook their own meals, take walks after dinner, and talk together
instead of just farming the kids out to the commercial culture.
Cooking at home, talking with kids, walking instead of driving,
involve less expenditure of money than do their commercial
counterparts. Solid marriages involve less expenditure for counseling
and divorce. Thus they are threats to the economy as portrayed in the
GDP. By that standard, the best kids are the ones who eat the most
junk food and exercise the least, because they will run up the biggest
medical bills for obesity and diabetes.

This assumption has been guiding our economic policies for the past
sixty years at least. Is it surprising that the family structure is
shaky, real community is in decline, and children have become petri
dishes of market-related dysfunction and disease? The nation conceives
of such things as growth and therefore good. It is not accidental that
the two major protest movements of recent decades–environmentalist and
pro-family–both deal with parts of the real economy that the GDP
leaves out and that the commercial culture that embodies the GDP tends
to erode. How did we get to this strange pass, where up is down and
down is up? How did it happen that the nation’s economic hero is a
terminal-cancer patient going through a costly divorce? How is it that
Congress talks about stimulating “the economy” when much that will
actually be stimulated is the destruction of things it says it cares
about on other days? How did the notion of economy become so totally
uneconomic?

The story begins in Ireland in the 1650s. British troops had just
repressed another uprising there, and the Cromwell government had
devised a final solution to put its Irish problem to rest. The
government would remove a significant portion of the populace–
Catholics in particular–to remote parts of the island. Then it would
redistribute their lands to British troops, thus providing
compensation to them and establishing an occupational presence for the
benefit of the government in London. The task of creating an inventory
of the lands went to an army physician by the name of William Petty, a
quick study and a man with an eye for the main chance. He classified
much land as marginal that actually was quite good. Then he got
himself appointed to the panel that made the distributions and
bestowed much of that land upon himself. Petty’s survey was the first
known attempt in Western history to create a total inventory of a
nation’s wealth. It was not done for the well-being of the Irish
people but rather to take their land away from them. It was an
instrument of government policy, and this has been true from that time
to the present. Governments have sought to catalogue the national
wealth for purposes of taxation, confiscation, planning, and
mobilization in times of war. They have not designed these catalogues
to be measures of national well-being or of quality of life. Yet that
is how the national wealth inventories have come to be used,
especially the GDP. Somehow the tool has become the task. This part of
the story begins with the Great Depression.

In the early 1930s, as the United States sank deeper into an economic
slough, Congress faced an absence of data to help guide the way out.
It didn’t know exactly what was happening and where. There were no
systematic figures on unemployment or production. President Herbert
Hoover had dispatched six employees from the Commerce Department to
travel around the country and file reports. These were anecdotal and
tended to support Hoover’s view that recovery was just around the
corner. Members of Congress wanted more. Senator Robert M. La Follette
Jr., a Republican of Wisconsin, introduced a resolution to require the
Commerce Department to develop a spreadsheet–as we would call it today–
of the economy with its component parts. La Follette was a Progressive
in the original sense. He believed in “scientific management and
planning,” and the resolution was to produce a tool to that end. It
passed in 1932, and the work fell to one Simon Kuznets, a professor
who was working at the National Bureau of Economic Research in New
York. Kuznets knew that he was producing a policy tool and not a
measure of living standards or well-being. As he put it later in his
clinical prose, the goal was to help understand the “relations and
relative importance of various parts of the productive system and
their responsiveness to various types of stimulae as shown by their
changes in the past.” Kuznets had a tiny staff and virtually no
budget. Data sources were fragmentary. But about a year and a half
later, Kuznets, with brevity and candor that are rare today, laid out
for Congress the limitations of the accounts he had constructed. He
took particular pains to tell you why you should not use these
accounts the way you–and the press–have come to use them.

For one thing, the national accounts leave out a crucial dimension of
the economy–the part that exists outside the realm of monetary
exchange. This segment includes both the ecosystem and the social
system–the life-supporting functions of the oceans and atmosphere, for
example, and work within families and communities that is not done for
money. So when the monetized economy displaces these elements–as when
both parents have to work, or when forest clearing eliminates the
cleansing function of trees–the losses are not subtracted against the
market gain. Kuznets was under no such illusion. “The volume of
services rendered by housewives and other members of the household
toward the satisfaction of wants must be imposing indeed,” he wrote.
There is also the question of what he called “odd jobs,” or what we
would call the “underground economy.” He knew these played a large
role in the economy. He also grasped, more broadly, that the quality
and importance of a function do not depend upon the amount of money
paid for it–or whether any money was paid at all. The care of a mother
and father is not inferior to that of a day-care worker just because
they do not charge a price for their services. This recognition
undercuts a basic assumption behind the GDP–namely, that the
contribution of an activity can be gauged solely by its market price.
But there is a practical problem, Kuznets observed. Accounts require
data, and there is by definition little data on the underground
economy and on nonmarket exchange. As a result, the national accounts
include only the slice of economic reality that falls within the
bandwidth that economists are able to grasp–recorded expenditures of
money.

Then there is the thorny question of constructive versus destructive
activities within the realm of monetized exchange. Once you have
decided to count only that which is transacted through money, do you
make the further assumption that everything transacted for money
counts on the plus side of the ledger? The mentality that lies behind
the GDP assumes that you do. We all are “rational,” so any choice we
make in the market is by definition one that makes our lives better.
Kuznets focused on one obvious exception: activities that are
generally illegal, such as gambling and selling drugs. To assume that
such expenditures add to the national well-being would undercut the
rationale for making them illegal in the first place. The GDP is an
instrument of the state, after all, so Kuznets drew the line there. He
was aware of how arbitrary this line is from an economic standpoint.
Why exactly does legal gambling add to well-being if the illegal kind
does not? Or what about alcohol? Given the assumption that legality
confers benediction, the economy received a huge boost at the end of
Prohibition, simply because the drinking that formerly was illegal now
was deemed permissible. But booze still was booze. If the government
can increase the growth rate by jiggering the metrics in this way,
that does not increase confidence in the validity of measure. But
legality is the easy part. Just beneath it lies a deeper issue–the
assumption that every purchase is beneficial simply because someone
has paid the purchase price. The exclusion of illegal activities,
Kuznets said, “does not imply… that all lawful pursuits are
necessarily serviceable from the social viewpoint.” He left the
question there, a chasm that honest inquiry has to plumb.

There are so many examples of expenditures that go into the GDP that
have a questionable claim to the stature of growth and good, even from
the standpoint of those who make them. For example, much consumption
is compulsory, in that buyers have little choice. There is fraud, such
as the way seniors are cheated in reverse-mortgage scams. There are
also products that are designed to lock buyers into an endless stream
of high-priced replacements, such as inkjet-printer cartridges that
are designed to resist refilling. There are car bumpers that are
designed not to bump, so that a mild fender bender turns into a $5,000
repair bill. There are the usurious charges and fees built into credit
cards. Not all Americans confronted with these expenditures regard
them as “consumption choices” that propel them further up a happy
mountain of more.

The toughest case for the economic mind is addiction. The GDP assumes,
as most economists do, that people are inherently “rational.” What
they buy is exactly what they want, and so their purchases must make
them happy in exact proportion to the prices paid. Yet addiction has
become pervasive. It has metastasized far beyond the usual suspects–
gambling, tobacco, alcohol, and drugs–and spread to such things as
eating, credit cards, and shopping itself. Also neglected is what
economists call “distribution.” The GDP makes no distinction between a
$500 dinner in Manhattan and the hundreds of more humble meals that
could be provided for the same amount. A socialite who buys a pair of
$800 pumps from Manolo Blahnik appears to contribute forty times more
to the national well-being than does the mother who buys a pair of $20
sneakers for her son at Payless. “Economic welfare,” Kuznets wrote,
“cannot be adequately measured unless the personal distribution of
income is known.” As included in the national accounts, an accretion
of luxury buying at the top covers up a lack of necessary buying at
the bottom. As the income scale becomes more skewed, the cover-up
becomes even greater. In this respect the GDP serves as a statistical
laundry operation that hides the suffering at the bottom. Another
problem has to do with work and the toll it takes on those who do it.
Kuznets called this the “reverse side of income, that is, the
intensity and unpleasantness of effort going into the earning of
income.” That earning comes at a cost of wear and tear upon the body
and psyche. If the GDP subtracts depreciation on buildings and
equipment, should there not be a corresponding subtraction for the
wearing out of people?

What about the loss in the value of their skills as one technology
displaces another? In the current accounting, this toll often gets
added to the GDP rather than subtracted, in the form of medications,
expenditures for retraining, and day care for children as parents work
longer hours. Most workers would regard such outlays as costs, not
gains. Had Kuznets been writing today, moreover, he probably would
have added another kind of depletion–that of natural resources. It
sounds incredible, but when this nation drills its oil and mines its
coal, the national accounts treat this as an addition to the national
wealth rather than a subtraction from it. The result is like a car
with a gas gauge that goes up as the fuel tank empties. The national
accounts portray a nation getting richer when it is in fact draining
itself dry. Kuznets concluded his report with words that ought to be
inscribed on the wall of every office on Capitol Hill and over every
computer screen within a twenty-mile radius: “The welfare of a nation
can, therefore, scarcely be inferred from a measurement of national
income as defined above.”

Congress and everybody else have done exactly what Kuznets urged us
not to do. The malpractice began with the gradual seep of the new
accounts into the political arena. In his 1936 reelection campaign,
Franklin Roosevelt noted that the economy–as defined by the national
accounts–had increased under his watch. It was a number: who could
resist? The likely source was FDR’s close adviser Harry Hopkins, whose
office was a hub for the young economists who came to Washington to
join the New Deal. But in the passage across 15th Street from the
Commerce Department to the White House, Kuznets’s numbers were turning
into precisely what he said they should not be. Then came World War
II, when the national accounts played a central role in the
mobilization effort. A bitter debate erupted in Washington over the
nation’s production goals. Corporate leaders insisted that the
mobilization must come out of the existing level of production. They
did not want to be stuck with excess capacity when the war was over.
Kuznets and others argued to the contrary that the United States had
vast troves of untapped capacity; they used the national accounts to
prove it. FDR sided with the “all-outers,” as this group was called.
They appealed to his belief in the energizing effects of challenges;
Roosevelt took their high estimates and made them even higher, the
better to make his point. (The planners then had to shift gears to
argue the case for system limits, which the national accounts also
helped them do.) Then the accounts helped to coordinate the war
production so as to prevent bottlenecks. By 1944 war production goals
alone had surpassed the nation’s entire output just ten years earlier.

It was as close as the nation has ever come to pure economic planning,
and though much reviled, it helped to win the war. Postwar surveys
revealed that Germany had no such planning tool, and Hitler’s
production program had been greatly hindered as a result. America had
become the “arsenal for democracy” in part through a top-down approach
made possible by the national accounts. As the war was winding down,
the accounts served again to guide the economy back to peacetime
without relapse into the dreaded Depression. Consumption was
essential; the Cold War, with its Pentagon spending, was not yet in
prospect. As war production diminished, shoppers would have to pick up
the slack. The national accounts showed exactly how it could be done.
As John Kenneth Galbraith put it in Fortune, “One good reason for
expecting prosperity after the war is the fact that we can lay down
its specifications.”

The new Keynesian economists such as Galbraith were now the Merlins of
prosperity, and the national accounts were their magic wand.
Consumption itself was taking on a heroic stature; the returning
troops were handing off the mantle of national purpose to the shoppers
who would replace them in keeping the industrial machinery in motion.
(The heroic imagery persists in the press today, as when we read that
consumers will provide the “engine” for recovery, or that they will
“pull” the nation out of its recession.) In this atmosphere, it was
perhaps inevitable that the map of the nation’s capacity would become
a totem to its economic success. Simon Kuznets watched it happen with
increasing dismay. (Galbraith came to have second thoughts as well.)
Kuznets was a quiet academic who was loath to mount a soapbox. But he
asserted over and over that those who had seized upon his handiwork
had missed the point. In 1962 he wrote in The New Republic that in
evaluating growth “distinctions must be kept in mind between quantity
and quality of growth, between its costs and return, and between the
short and the long run…. Goals for ‘more’ growth should specify more
growth of what and for what.” If you are going to “stimulate” the
economy, in other words, could we at least have a little debate over
what exactly you are going to stimulate?

The purpose of an economy is to meet human needs in such a way that
life becomes in some respect richer and better in the process. It is
not simply to produce a lot of stuff. Stuff is a means, not an end.
Yet current modes of economic measurement focus almost entirely on
means. For example, an automobile is productive if it produces
transportation. But today we look only at the cars produced per hour
worked. More cars can mean more traffic and therefore a transportation
system that is less productive. The medical system is the same. The
aim should be healthy people, not the sale of more medical services
and drugs. Now, however, we assess the economic contribution of the
medical system on the basis of treatments rather than results.
Economists see nothing wrong with this. They see no problem that the
medical system is expected to produce 30 to 40 percent of new jobs
over the next thirty years. “We have to spend our money on something,”
shrugged a Stanford economist to the New York Times. This is more
insanity. Next we will be hearing about “disease-led recovery.” To
stimulate the economy we will have to encourage people to be sick so
that the economy can be well.
Reply all
Reply to author
Forward
0 new messages