What wouldn’t change (according to MMT):
MMT view: Reserve currency status isn’t what enables spending—monetary sovereignty is.
But some real consequences could occur:
Key MMT Voices:
Warren Mosler says reserve status is the result of U.S. trade deficits—not a condition for funding.
Stephanie Kelton has said reserve currency status is overrated; countries demand dollars because they want safe assets, not because we need their money.
Bottom line (MMT view):
Losing reserve currency status wouldn’t stop the U.S. from spending or cause insolvency.
But it could lead to a weaker dollar, higher import prices, and less global influence.
The real constraint remains inflation, not foreign creditors.
Best,
Jason
The US losing reserve status in the future is a topic amongst some including personal friends and family.
I did a little digging and tried to find an MMT informed analysis and the following came up:What wouldn’t change (according to MMT):
- The U.S. would still be monetarily sovereign.
- It issues its own floating fiat currency (the U.S. dollar) and can never run out of dollars or be forced to default on dollar-denominated debt.
- The U.S. government doesn’t need foreign currency or borrowing to spend. Foreign countries buying Treasuries is a savings decision—not a funding requirement for U.S. spending.
MMT view: Reserve currency status isn’t what enables spending—monetary sovereignty is.
But some real consequences could occur:
- Weaker dollar over time:
If fewer countries need to hold dollars or Treasuries, demand could fall and the dollar could gradually weaken.
- Imported inflation:
A weaker dollar makes imports more expensive (especially energy and raw materials). This could raise inflation, which MMT sees as the true constraint on government spending.
- Reduced global pricing power:
The U.S. might lose some influence over global pricing of oil,
- Interest rate impact (maybe):
If global demand for Treasuries drops, rates could rise—but MMT emphasizes that the Fed still controls interest rates and can keep them low by purchasing government debt if necessary.
Key MMT Voices:
Warren Mosler says reserve status is the result of U.S. trade deficits—not a condition for funding.
Stephanie Kelton has said reserve currency status is overrated; countries demand dollars because they want safe assets, not because we need their money.
Bottom line (MMT view):
Losing reserve currency status wouldn’t stop the U.S. from spending or cause insolvency.
But it could lead to a weaker dollar, higher import prices, and less global influence.
The real constraint remains inflation, not foreign creditors.
--
Best,
Jason
You received this message because you are subscribed to the Google Groups "Modern Monetary Theory" group.
To unsubscribe from this group and stop receiving emails from it, send an email to modern-monetary-t...@googlegroups.com.
To view this discussion visit https://groups.google.com/d/msgid/modern-monetary-theory/D2E97299-044F-4A08-89FE-D44168E3C904%40gmail.com.
Ryan: Hold USD reserves → Weaken local currency → Cheaper exports → More U.S. demand
+ Reserves facilitate trade + finance U.S. deficits → Sustain U.S. import appetite
Here’s a ChatGPT analysis with China in mind:
🇨🇳 China’s USD Reserve Strategy to Boost Exports
1. Currency Management: Keeping the Yuan Weak
📉 Example: In the 2000s, China tightly controlled the exchange rate (≈8 RMB per USD), helping drive the U.S. trade deficit with China to hundreds of billions annually.
2. Massive U.S. Treasury Purchases (Vendor Financing)
💡 Think of it like this: China sells goods to Americans, earns dollars, and then lends those dollars back to the U.S. so Americans can keep buying more.
3. Trade and Payment Simplicity
4. Export-Led Growth Model
Net Effect:
China recycles its trade surplus into USD reserves → Holds down the yuan → Keeps exports cheap → Enables U.S. consumption → Drives even more exports.
This cycle helped power China’s rapid industrialization—and is one of the reasons the U.S. has run persistent trade deficits with China since the 1990s.
Luke,
A weaker dollar boosts U.S. manufacturing competitiveness, supports export growth, and may lead to more domestic investment and jobs—especially in tradable goods sectors.
A weaker dollar helps but does not eliminate core structural challenges:
👉 The path forward isn’t to out-China China. It’s to specialize, automate, and strategically choose what to bring home—not everything.
✅ Most Likely to Return or Expand in the U.S.
Sector | Why It Can Compete |
Semiconductors | Strategic priority (CHIPS Act), high-tech, low labor input, national security concern |
Aerospace & Defense | Advanced engineering, national security, high-value exports (e.g., Boeing, Raytheon) |
Pharmaceuticals & Biotech | High profit margins, intellectual property–driven, reshoring incentives after COVID |
Electric Vehicles & Batteries | Green energy push, automation-friendly, massive federal and state subsidies |
Industrial Machinery & Tools | Capital-intensive, durable goods, close-to-market demand (e.g., Caterpillar, John Deere) |
Medical Devices | Highly regulated, quality-sensitive, increasingly reshored for resilience |
Specialty Chemicals | U.S. advantage in cheap energy (natural gas), environmental controls for sensitive production |
⚖️ Possibly Reshored (Under Right Conditions)
Sector | Challenges/Opportunities |
Apparel Prototyping & Fast Fashion | U.S. unlikely to produce bulk T-shirts, but small-batch, quick-turnaround production may reshore with automation |
Consumer Electronics Assembly | High labor content, but firms like Apple are exploring some U.S. production for final assembly (e.g., Mac Pro in Texas) |
Automotive | Some reshoring already happening (especially EVs), but dependent on labor costs, union pressure |
Furniture & Home Goods | Possible for high-end/custom pieces; bulk production still favors Asia |
🚫 Least Likely to Return in Bulk
Sector | Why It Won’t Likely Reshore |
Textiles (Mass Production) | Extremely low margins, high labor cost gap (Bangladesh, Vietnam) |
Plastic Toys & Basic Goods | Low skill, highly commodified, cost-driven |
Basic Electronics & Components | Complex global supply chains, heavily centered in East Asia |
Low-End Appliances | Brands rely on global volume and razor-thin margins, often made in Mexico/China |
🧭 Key Takeaways
- Jason
On Jun 18, 2025, at 7:47 AM, Luke Lucas <galio...@gmail.com> wrote:Would a weakened dollar be good for US manufacturing? Allow US companies to expand?
Luke,
A weaker dollar boosts U.S. manufacturing competitiveness, supports export growth, and may lead to more domestic investment and jobs—especially in tradable goods sectors.
To view this discussion visit https://groups.google.com/d/msgid/modern-monetary-theory/53D4DB97-688D-4053-8E9A-4E2696D6DE3E%40gmail.com.